• Tag Archives Murray Rothbard
  • Money-Supply Growth Drops Again – Falls to 108-Month Low

    Growth in the supply of US dollars fell again in August, this time to a 108-month low of 4.2 percent. The last time the money supply grew at a smaller rate was during August 2008 – at a rate of 4.1 percent.
    The money-supply metric used here – an “Austrian money supply” measure – is the metric developed by Murray Rothbard and Joseph Salerno, and is designed to provide a better measure than M2. The Mises Institute now offers regular updates on this metric and its growth.
    The “Austrian” measure of the money supply differs from M2 in that it includes treasury deposits at the Fed (and excludes short time deposits, traveler’s checks, and retail money funds).
    M2 growth also slowed in August, falling to 5.3 percent, a 75-month low.

    This post was published at Ludwig von Mises Institute on Sept 18, 2017.


  • For a New Libertarian

    [This talk was delivered at the 2017 Mises University.]
    Greetings to everyone at the Corax 2017 conference, and greetings also to the audience here at our annual Mises University. As you can see both events are happening simultaneously, so I couldn’t be with you in person this evening. But I very much appreciate being invited by Sofia and Martin to speak, and I would indeed have joined you in Malta any other week. And I admire Sofia and Martin for having the courage to leave Sweden and start this new venture in Malta, which by their account is not only warmer but also far more reasonable!
    What I’d like to talk about today is libertarians, more than libertarianism itself. And I’ll ask you to consider whether libertarians have lost their way.
    The title ‘For a New Libertarian’ is I hope an obvious play on the title of Murray Rothbard’s famous book For a New Liberty. It’s an underrated book, less well-known perhaps than The Ethics of Liberty. Lots of authors have the ego to call their books ‘a manifesto,’ but few books actually live up to such an bold subtitle. This book does.
    I love Murray’s line: ‘libertarianism, then, is a philosophy seeking a policy.’ I wonder if he’d change that line today, if he could see where the ‘public policy’ branch of libertarianism has become. Or maybe he should have written ‘libertarianism is a philosophy seeking better libertarians.’
    I also chose the title to make the important point that we don’t need a ‘new libertarianism’ or anything so grand. Thanks to the great thinkers who came before us, and still among us, we don’t have to do the hard work – which is good news, because not many of us are smart enough to come up with new theory! We can all very happily serve as second-hand dealers in ideas.

    This post was published at Ludwig von Mises Institute on July 29, 2017.


  • Money Supply Growth Falls Again, Dropping to 105-Month Low

    Growth in the supply of US dollars fell again in May, this time to a 105-month low of 5.4 percent. The last time the money supply grew at a smaller rate was during September 2008 – at a rate of 5.2 percent.
    The money-supply metric used here – an “Austrian money supply” measure – is the metric developed by Murray Rothbard and Joseph Salerno, and is designed to provide a better measure than M2. The Mises Institute now offers regular updates on this metric and its growth.
    The “Austrian” measure of the money supply differs from M2 in that it includes treasury deposits at the Fed (and excludes short time deposits, traveler’s checks, and retail money funds).
    M2 growth also slowed in May, falling to 5.6 percent, a 20-month low.

    This post was published at Ludwig von Mises Institute on July 21, 2017.


  • Our Lawless Central Bank

    The economic arguments against central banks are numerous to say the least. Through the writings of Ludwig von Mises and Murray Rothbard we have a wide variety of critiques that explain the many ways the central banks distort economies, cause booms and busts, punish savers, and chose winners and losers through monetary policy.
    But, even if confronted with these arguments, and one remains supportive of central banks, other non-economic arguments must still be addressed.
    For example, it is becoming increasing important – in our current age of “non-traditional” monetary policy – to take note of the fact that central banks, and especially the Federal Reserve, are essentially unrestrained by law.
    Economists themselves often defend this total unmooring from legal or political accountability, saying it is necessary for the Fed to have “independence” from elected officials.
    In reality, however, this “independence” is best described as “total lack of accountability.”
    Writing in today’s Dallas Morning News, Texas Tech economist Alexander William Salter writes:

    This post was published at Ludwig von Mises Institute on 06/22/2017.


  • Government as the Source of Monopoly: US Airlines Edition

    “Is Government the Source of Monopoly?” asked Chicago economist Yale Brozen in an essay first published in 1968. Yes, he answered – not only directly, by awarding exclusive licenses and contracts, but also indirectly, via regulation, minimum-wage legislation, and other forms of government intervention. Austrian economists such as Murray Rothbard and Dominick Armentano went further, arguing that monopoly per se is impossible on the free market, as long as government does not restrict entry into markets. More successful firms will tend to grow and increase their market share, but this does not constitute monopoly, as long as other firms are free to compete, or try to compete. The concept of monopoly only makes sense, theoretically and empirically, when the government protects privileged firms from competition, either directly or through the kinds of indirect means discussed by Brozen.
    I recently came across a lucid example of government-created monopoly in Thomas Petzinger excellent book Hard Landing: The Epic Contest for Power and Profits That Plunged the Airlines into Chaos (Crown, 1996). Petzinger explains the emergence of the US commercial airline industry in the 1930s as the result of efforts by Walter F. Brown, Postmaster General in the Hoover Administration, to reorganize the nascent airmail business.

    This post was published at Ludwig von Mises Institute on June 17, 2017.


  • How We Should Name Business Cycles

    Economists have long played semantic games with business cycles. In particular, they try to downplay the significance of the crisis and to obfuscate its cause.
    First of all, bubbles and economic crises are initially denied and then usually not named until after they end and particular sectors of the economy are revealed to be what Lionel Robbins called ‘a cluster of entrepreneurial errors.’
    The housing bubble was an exception because it was obvious to Austrian economists that there was a bubble as early as 2002 and that it was concentrated in housing due to various government subsidies, tax breaks, and regulations.
    Murray Rothbard explained that economists have played semantic games regarding the naming of business cycles. Up until the Great Depression an economic crisis typically started with a boom, followed by a ‘panic’ and concluded with a ‘depression.’
    After the disaster of 1929, economists and politicians resolved that this (i.e., a ‘depression’) must never happen again. The easiest way of succeeding at this resolve was simply to define ‘depression’ out of existence. From this point on, America was to suffer no further depressions.

    This post was published at Ludwig von Mises Institute on June 16, 2017.


  • Bitcoin — Your Newest, Most Powerful Tool of Subversion

    Murray Rothbard often described the government as a ‘gang of thieves writ large.’
    His description captures the State’s true essence… coercion.
    Any government, anywhere in the world, and at any time in history is simply a group of people with a monopoly on coercion in a certain geographic area. That’s it.
    It doesn’t matter if it’s a democracy, monarchy, dictatorship, or something else.
    Government is not about selfless public servants advancing some vague common good. It’s about brute force.
    They don’t teach this in public schools. But it’s true.

    This post was published at International Man


  • Are Central Banks Worthy of Trust?

    In an essay on Edmund Burke’s view of the nature of government, Murray Rothbard quoted him as saying:
    In vain you tell me that Artificial Government is good, but that I fall out only with the Abuse. The Thing! The Thing itself is the Abuse!”
    Our complaint isn’t just with “abuse of the system,” it is with the system itself! The system is the abuse. Everything else is a symptom, a surface issue.
    When BOE Governor Mark Carney spoke on various banking sector abuses at the Banking Standards Board Panel, he misses the entire point. The title of the speech is ‘Worthy of trust? Law, ethics and culture in banking’ and he is concerned that such abuses have produced a “crisis of legitimacy.”
    “This immense progress has been overshadowed by a crisis of legitimacy. A series of scandals ranging from mis-selling to manipulation have undermined trust in banking, the financial system, and, to some degree, markets themselves.”
    Bad behaviour went unchecked, proliferated and eventually became the norm.

    This post was published at Ludwig von Mises Institute on March 24, 2017.


  • Money Supply Growth Falls to 17-month Low in February

    The supply of US dollars has slowed during early 2017 with February’s year-over-year percentage increase hitting a 17-month low of 7.7 percent. Monthly year-over-year growth rates in the money supply have been falling each month since October.
    Over the past eight months or so, money supply growth rates have become somewhat volatile with the growth rate surging from 6.7 percent in late 2017 up to 11.3 percent by late 2016, and down again to under 8 percent by February of this year.
    This recent period of volatility comes after a long period of relatively sedate and consistent growth in the money supply through most of 2013, 2014, and 2015.
    The “Austrian” money supply measure (AMS) used here is a measure of the money supply pioneered by Murray Rothbard and Joseph Salerno and is designed to provide a better measure than M2. The Mises Institute now offers regular updates on this metric and its growth.
    The “Austrian” measure of the money supply differs from M2 in that it includes treasury deposits at the Fed (and excludes short time deposits, traveler’s checks, and retail money funds).
    Since 2014, money supply growth has ranged from about 7 percent to 8.5 percent. In October of last year, money supply growth hit a seven-year low of 6.8 percent, although this proved not to be an indication of any new trend.

    This post was published at Ludwig von Mises Institute on March 23, 2017.


  • Can state spending ever be cut?

    President Trump was elected on several promises, including one that he would fund tax cuts by cutting public spending. Cynics might note that his first action was to increase spending on the military by $54bn, the equivalent of six Polish armies. This is not a good start. Trump is hailed, in some quarters, as a latter-day Reagan, a Republican president who understood the impotence of the state, and how it is a burden on free enterprise. This is not a good precedent either.
    Taxes and deficits increased under Reagan. As Murray Rothbard put it in a 1988 retrospective on Reagan’s years in the White House:
    ‘In the first place, the famous tax cut of 1981 did not cut taxes at all. It’s true that tax rates for higher income tax brackets were cut; but for the average person, taxes rose, rather than declined. The reason was that, on the whole, the cut in income tax rates was more than offset by two forms of tax increase. One was ‘bracket creep,’ a term for inflation quietly but effectively raising one into higher tax brackets, so that you pay more and proportionately higher taxes even though the tax rate schedule has officially remained the same. The second source of higher taxes was Social Security taxation, which kept increasing, and which helped taxes go up overall.’

    This post was published at GoldMoney on MARCH 16, 2017.


  • Money Supply Growth Moderated in December

    In our last update on money supply – using the “Austrian” measure of money supply developed by Murray Rothbard and Joseph Salerno – we found that money supply growth hit a 46-month high of 11.2 percent in October.
    Growth has moderated since then, however, with year-over-year growth in US dollars dropping to 10.3 percent in November and 8.8 percent in December.
    This change somewhat follows a change in M2 over the same time period as 1M2 growth hit a multi-year high of 7.5 percent in October, but fell to 7.3 percent and 7.0 percent in November and December, respectively.

    This post was published at Ludwig von Mises Institute on February 4, 2017.


  • Crisis and Legitimacy: The Fork in the Road

    Remnant Review
    Those of us who are known as conspiracy historians argue that the Council on Foreign Relations, the Trilateral Commission, and various other high-level elite societies provide most of the leadership at the national level of the United States. In other words, we think that the system is rigged.
    At the same time, we are well aware of the fact that the general public is persuaded that there are significant issues at stake politically, and once every four years the voters wake up from their slumber, and they get interested in who wins the Presidency. Then they go back to sleep. Those of us who are conspiracy historians don’t think the elections make much difference in terms of the overall direction in which the nation is moving.
    Nevertheless, there are times in history, which generally are times of crisis, in which fundamentally new political procedures and new political ideas that begin to shape the direction in which a nation is moving. The election of 1912 was such an election, but even more important was the Spanish-American War (1898), which launched a new era of empire for the United States. The key figure in all of this was Teddy Roosevelt.
    The next major change was the Great Depression. Politically, it looked as though Hoover and Roosevelt had radically different programs. In fact, they were both Progressives. If anything, in 1932 Hoover was the more radical. The public thought it was making a fundamental decision in 1932 when it voted for Roosevelt, but the New Deal was simply an extension of what Hoover had already begun to construct. On this, read Murray Rothbard’s book, America’s Great Depression (1963).
    Obviously, the atomic bomb changed the nature of warfare and therefore changed the nature of conflict between empires. Next, the collapse of the Soviet Union in 1991 made the United States the sole superpower. This has now degenerated into a series of no-win wars, and these wars are against non-state combatants. We do not know how this is going to turn out, except to say that at some point, the United States government is not going to be able to afford to maintain its present empire. At that point, there will be a fundamental reconsideration of the United States as the world’s only superpower. In all likelihood there is not going to be a single superpower. But we don’t know that for certain.

    This post was published at Gary North on January 04, 2017.


  • Money Creation and the Boom-Bust Cycle

    In his various writings, Murray Rothbard argued that in a free market economy that operates on a gold standard the creation of credit that is not fully backed up by gold (fractional-reserve banking) sets in motion the menace of the boom-bust cycle. In his The Case for 100 Percent Gold Dollar Rothbard wrote,
    I therefore advocate as the soundest monetary system and the only one fully compatible with the free market and with the absence of force or fraud from any source a 100 percent gold standard. This is the only system compatible with the fullest preservation of the rights of property. It is the only system that assures the end of inflation and, with it, of the business cycle.1
    Some economists such as George Selgin and Lawrence White have contested this view. In his article in The Independent Review George Selgin argued that it is not true that fractional-reserve banking must always set in motion the menace of the boom-bust cycle.

    This post was published at Ludwig von Mises Institute on January 3, 2016.


  • Central Bankers Are Losing Faith in Their Own Alchemy

    Mervyn King is the British Ben Bernanke. An eminent academic economist, who now teaches both at New York University and the London School of Economics, King was from 2003 to 2013 Governor of the Bank of England. In short, he is a very big deal. Remarkably, in The End of Alchemy he frequently sounds like Murray Rothbard.
    King identifies a basic problem in the banking system that has again and again led to financial crisis. ‘The idea that paper money could replace intrinsically valuable gold and precious metals, and that banks could take secure short-term deposits and transform them into long-term risky investments came into its own with the Industrial Revolution in the eighteenth century. It was both revolutionary and immensely seductive. It was in fact financial alchemy – the creation of extraordinary financial powers that defy reality and common sense. Pursuit of this monetary elixir has brought a series of economic disasters – from hyperinflation to banking collapses.’
    How exactly is this alchemy supposed to work? ‘People believed in alchemy because, so it was argued, depositors would never all choose to withdraw their money at the same time. If depositors’ requirements to make payments or obtain liquidity were, when averaged over a large number of depositors, a predictable flow, then deposits could provide a reliable source of long-term funding. But if a sizable group of depositors were to withdraw funds at the same time, the bank would be forced either to demand immediate repayment of the loans it had made, … or to default on the claims of depositors.’ Readers of Rothbard’s What Has Government Done to Our Money? will recognize a familiar theme.

    This post was published at Ludwig von Mises Institute on December 29, 2016.


  • Economic Science Has Been Hijacked

    In Principles of Economics, Carl Menger corrected the theoretical mistakes made by the old classical school. At the time, the founder of the Austrian school of economics seemed to want to make economics accessible to everyday people, which may explain why he exemplified the nature of economic value in his book, making sure readers understood that economics revolves around the actions of individuals.
    Described by many as ‘the best introduction to economic logic ever written,’ Menger’s Principles inspired young economists like Ludwig von Mises to explore the populist nature of economics in an attempt to make the case that economics was for everyone, and that practical knowledge of economics can help even the most uneducated among us to prosper.
    Despite the honorable efforts and the exponential growth of influence the Austrian school of economics has exerted over the years, the reality is that, for most individuals around the globe, economics is hard.
    Murray Rothbard, the late Austrian economist and scholar, famously wrote in 1970 that it is no ‘crime to be ignorant of economics,’ after all, he added, most people see economics as a ‘dismal science.’ Nevertheless, he concluded, ‘it is totally irresponsible to have a loud and vociferous opinion on economic subjects while remaining in this state of ignorance.’

    This post was published at Ludwig von Mises Institute on Dec 17, 2016.


  • Taxation Isn’t Only Theft, It’s Destruction

    Where the state is, there is the power to tax; for rulers cannot rule without taxation. As Ludwig von Mises wrote: “The funds that a government spends for whatever purposes are levied by taxation.” Or as Murray Rothbard put it: “All state actions rest on the fundamental binary intervention of taxes.”
    Where the state is, there also is the growth of the state. Why does a state’s scope enlarge? One theory is that interest groups seek to use the state’s taxing power for their own benefit. I would like to suggest a complementary theory. When the power to tax is conferred upon rulers, many harmful incentives necessarily are conveyed with it. These encourage the rulers to expand their destructive acts.
    Incentives Purposeful action involves choice among alternatives. Choices embed incentives (rewards) and disincentives (costs), both of which can be monetary or non-monetary. Consider, for example, the Crown’s provision of justice in medieval England. Convicted felons were typically hanged and their goods forfeited to the Crown, although the King might pardon a felon who agreed to serve in the Royal army. This incentive structure motivated the Crown to convict felons, because for each conviction the payment was either the felon’s property or use of the felon as a soldier (the incentives). The Crown faced disincentives too, not only out-of-pocket costs but also disloyalty, disaffection, loss of reputation and resentment, if it wrongly convicted innocent people of felonies.
    Under this incentive structure, the Crown likely displays a marked enthusiasm for arresting and convicting felons (and perhaps non-felons). The incentive structure also induces the Crown to change the laws so as to define more crimes as felonies. If this dynamic sounds similar to the case of police and municipalities in the United States benefiting from the seizure and forfeiture of goods and the resulting expansion of crimes subject to seizure and forfeiture, that is because it is.

    This post was published at Ludwig von Mises Institute on December 9, 2016.


  • The Case Against Central Banking

    The following video was published by SilverDoctors on Dec 6, 2016
    Speaking at the Future of Freedom 5th Anniversary Conference on September 24, 1994, Roger Garrison, professor of economics at Auburn University, explores critiques of central banking from a number of perspectives. He summarizes the history of central banking, as well as the battle between the Keynesians, the monetarists (such as Milton Friedman), and the Austrians (including Murray Rothbard). Garrison’s talk is a great and accessible introduction to central banking and monetary policy.


  • Electing “the Right People” Won’t Fix Washington, DC

    The 2016 presidential circus isn’t over with yet, but no matter the result it has already proven to be a frustrating electoral season for libertarians. Both Senator Rand Paul’s and former Governor Gary Johnson’s campaigns have disappointed most of their respective bases, and it now seems uncertain whether Johnson will achieve the 5% national goal the Libertarian Party to help them in future campaigns. What lessons should libertarians learn?
    Perhaps the most important takeaway is that the goal of a libertarian savior riding into Washington and saving the day is an inherently foolish one. This goal overlooks how bureaucratic and indissoluble most of the Federal government has become. As opposed to Congressman Ron Paul’s Presidential campaign, which focused primarily on educating people on issues such as the Federal Reserve and blowback, both Senator Paul’s and Governor Johnson’s focused on the personal value each would bring to the White House and an implicit promise that they could make the beltway more libertarian.
    But libertarians need to realize that Washington isn’t salvageable, for reasons Ludwig von Mises well understood.
    While Murray Rothbard loved to hate the state, Ludwig von Mises did not. Throughout his life, Mises was a champion of liberal minarchism and believed that a watchman state was necessary for the protection of private property and individual liberty. But as an uncompromising advocate for free markets and fierce opponent of central planning, Mises was well aware of the dangers of a professional governing class isolated from accountability.
    Anyone who has read his book Bureaucracy, or any other of his works related to the subject, knows the disdain Mises held for this professional class of government workers. Bureaucratic, tyrannical governments were disastrous – not necessarily due to the character of the individuals involved – but due to the stifling nature of the government bureaucracy:

    This post was published at Ludwig von Mises Institute on Nov 2, 2016.


  • Rothbard on the glorious effects of falling prices

    Deflation has a bad name among today’s economists, and this should be your first clue that it might be something good. These educated Keynesians, as we’ve seen, can’t see a bubble until it explodes in their faces, at which time their zombie economy starts to wobble and nightmare possibilities abound, the worst being ‘it’ might happen, as it did in the 1930s. They immediately turn to god (the FED chair) and pray that he or she will do what is right. As we know, Ben Bernanke built his reputation making sure “it” doesn’t happen here.
    In a speech delivered in circa 1976 and reprinted in The Rothbard Reader, Murray Rothbard gives us a different view of deflation. First, what is it? Deflation is falling prices, he says, veering for the sake of discussion from the usual Austrian school definition as a contraction in the supply of money. Even Bernanke could accept deflation defined as falling prices. What he doesn’t accept is another assertion of Rothbard’s: The trend in an unhampered free market economy is usually a falling price level. It’s the unhampered part Bernanke can’t digest. Unhampered would mean no FED, no FDIC, freedom of people to choose the money they wish to use – the usual unthinkable conditions for Keynesians.
    Rothbard could think of those things quite naturally. Falling prices are ‘glorious effects’ of a robust free market, ‘even in the face of our general inflationary trend.’

    This post was published at GoldSeek on 5 October 2016.